SFeDu
  • Home
  • Issues
  • 2023
  • No 1
  • Was seventeenth-century British political arithmetic a precursor of nineteenth-century economic science?

Was seventeenth-century British political arithmetic a precursor of nineteenth-century economic science?


TERRA ECONOMICUS, , Vol. 21 (no. 1),

The 19th-century English economist W.S.Jevons revisited the work of Gregory King. A seventeenth-century follower of Sir Francis Bacon, King had described in a brief empirical observation how price correlated with supply. The history of seventeenth-century commercial mathematics, this essay suggests, provides essential background for understanding the empirical observation which Jevons received from King. The 17th century was the pivot time during which new techniques appeared in higher mathematics, calculus and mathematical probability among them. Higher mathematics incorporated innovations which had previously appeared in commercial mathematics, Arabic numerals, pen and paper calculations, new notations, etc. At the same time, ancient Greek higher mathematics continued for a while, and Gregory King also borrowed some calculations from James Ussher who used ancient Greek higher mathematics. King learned Bacon’s empirical method from John Graunt and Sir William Petty, and all three represented a stage of political arithmetic which was midway between Bacon’s simple empiricism on the one hand and later mathematical probability and random sampling on the other hand. In this midway stage, statesmen made policy while taking care to obtain data from professional advisors whom they employed. The advisors based their advice at first on a combination of observation, skill, and intuition, but then later they added commercial arithmetic.
Citation: Taylor J.A. (2023). Was seventeenth-century British political arithmetic a precursor of nineteenth-century economic science? Terra Economicus 21(1), 32–46. DOI: 10.18522/2073- 6606-2023-21-1-32-46


Keywords: commercial mathematics; shop arithmetic; political arithmetic; mathematical probability; James Ussher; Sir William Petty; John Graunt; Gregory King; William Stanley Jevons; Ancient Greek Higher Mathematics

JEL codes: B11; B12

References:
  • Bardi, J. (2009). The Calculus Wars: Newton, Leibniz, and the Greatest Mathematical Clash of All Time. New York: Basic Books.
  • Barrett, J. (2016). Mathematical Source References: Original Source References for Common Mathematical Ideas. Unpublished manuscript. https://eprints.soton.ac.uk/398356/1/2016%2520Mathematical%2520Source%2520References.pdf (accessed: October 17, 2022).
  • Berkeley, G. (1754). The Analyst. London: Tonson.
  • Buck, S. (1999). Hans Holbein. Cologne, Germany: Könemann.
  • Butterfield, H. (1957). The Origins of Modern Science. New York: Free Press.
  • Churchill, W. (2014). Marlborough: His Life and Times. 4 vols. New York: Rosetta Books.
  • Daston, L. (1988). Classical Probability in the Enlightenment. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Davenant, Ch. (1771). The Political and Commercial Works. Ed. by Whitworth, Ch., 5 vols., vol. 2. London: Horsfield.
  • Deane, P. (2008). Political Arithmetic. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. DOI: 10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1313-2
  • Dee, J. (2004). The Limits of the British Empire. Ed. by MacMillan, K., Abeles, J. Westport, CT: Praeger.
  • Diogenes Laërtius (2015). Complete Works. East Sussex: Delphi Classics.
  • Evans, G. (1967). The law of demand —The roles of Gregory King and Charles Davenant, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 81, 483–492.
  • Graunt, J. (1973). Natural and political observations and conclusions upon the Bills of Mortality 1662. In: Laslett, P. (ed.) The Earliest Classics. Westmead: Gregg International.
  • Harward, J. (ed.) (1932). The Platonic Epistles. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Hooper, M. (2011). At the House of the Magician. London: Bloomsbury.
  • Hoppit, J. (1996). Political Arithmetic in Eighteenth-Century England. Economic History Review, New Series 49(3), 516–540.
  • Jevons, W. (1863). A Serious Fall in the Value of Gold Ascertained, and its Social Effects Set Forth. London: Edward Stanford.
  • Jevons, W. (1865). The Coal Question. London: Macmillan
  • Jevons, W. (1866). Brief Account of a General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy. The Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 29(6), 282–87.
  • Jevons, W. (1871). The Theory of Political Economy. London: Macmillan.
  • Kim, J. (1995). Jevons versus Cairnes on exact economic laws. In: Rima, I (ed.) Measurement, Quantification and Economic Analysis: Numeracy in Economics. London: Routledge, pp. 140–156. DOI: 10.4324/9780203031056
  • King, G. (1973). Natural and political observations and conclusions. In: Laslett, P. (ed.) The Earliest Classics. Westmead: Gregg International.
  • Laslett, P. (ed.) (1973). The Earliest Classics. Westmead: Gregg International.
  • Lehman, G., Weinman, M. (2018). The Parthenon and Liberal Education. Albany: SUNY Press.
  • McCormick, T. (2006). Alchemy in the political arithmetic of Sir William Petty (1623–1687). Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part A 37(2), 290–307. DOI: 10.1016/j.shpsa.2005.07.012
  • McCormick, T. (2014). Political arithmetic’s 18th century histories: Quantification in politics, religion, and the public sphere. History Compass 12, 239–251. DOI: 10.1111/hic3.12144
  • Merton, R. (2001). Science, Technology & Society in Seventeenth-Century England. New York: Howard Fertig.
  • Merzbach, U., Boyer, C. (2011). A History of Mathematics. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.
  • Mueller, I. (2005). Mathematics and the divine in Plato. In: Koetsier, T., Bergmans, l. (eds.) Mathematics and the Divine: A Historical Study. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 99–121.
  • Nicomachus of Gerasa et al. (1926). Introduction to Arithmetic. New York: Macmillan.
  • Petty, W. (1899). Economic Writings. Ed. by Hull, Ch. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Project Gutenberg (2012). Jevons, Stanley. Encyclopaedia Britannica, vol. 15, slice 4. https://www.gutenberg.org/cache/epub/41055/pg41055-images.html#ar1 (accessed: December 11, 2022).
  • Roncaglia, A. (2017). A Brief History of Economic Thought. New York: Cambridge University Press.
  • Taylor, J. (1996). Gregory King’s analysis of clerical living for John Chamberlayne and the governors of Queen Anne’s Bounty. The Historical Journal (39): 241.
  • Taylor, J. (2005). British Empiricism and Early Political Economy: Gregory King’s 1696 Estimates of National Wealth and Population. Westport, CT: Praeger.
  • Taylor, J. (2019). Adam Smith’s seventeenth-century sources. Terra Economicus 17(3), 78–88.
  • Voltaire (1733). Letter XVII. On infinities in geometry, and Sir Isaac Newton’s chronology. In: Letters Concerning the English Nation. London: Printed for C. Davis in Pater-Noster-Row and A. Lyon in Russel-Street Covent Garden, pp. 151–165.
  • Yates, F. (1983). The Occult Philosophy in the Elizabethan Age. London: Ark Paperbacks.
Publisher: Southern Federal University
Founder: Southern Federal University
ISSN: 2073-6606