SFeDu

THE RISE OF METRICS

TERRA ECONOMICUS, , Vol. 16 (no. 4),

Metrics have become an increasingly important social institution. In particular, Neoliberal economic policy have emphasized the role of metrics. Such types of metrics as key performance indicators, rankings and various indices are used for improved economic coordination and motivation in the private and especially in the public sectors of the economy. In the context of Neoliberal economic policy, metrics complement, and sometimes replace, market coordination. The use of metrics is usually justified by the need for quantitative benchmarks both to promote competition and control it. Neoliberalism supports application of performance indicators, which do not expand opportunities, but guide the choice so the latter is constrained by a given framework, with the role of bureaucratic regulation strengthened. The use of metrics in ideology and economic policy results in a lock-in effect, supporting the concept of the institutional trap of metrics. The use of quantitative indicators could be attributed to the lack of priority of social and organizational values, and their role for coordination of repetitive social interactions. Two levels of metrics are suggested as including vertical and baseline ones. The applicability of metrics is limited by the scale of the activity they are intended to coordinate, and by the characteristics of the institutional environment. Baseline metrics are designed by experts who have explicit and implicit knowledge on the functioning of specific departments of an organization and specific production processes. In contrast, vertical metrics are designed by managers who neither possesses sufficient information and implicit knowledge, nor rooted in the profession. Higher education can be suggested as an example of widespread use of metrics for regulatory, incentive and monitoring purposes. To reduce negative effects for higher education, baseline metrics, which are complementary to professional values, are suggested to replace the vertical ones.


Keywords: metrics; Neoliberal policy; New Public Management; institutional change; technological change; vertical metrics; baseline metrics; institutional trap of metrics

References:
  • Arthur, W. B. (1989). Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical Events // The Economic Journal, 99(394), 116–131. DOI: 10.2307/2234208.
  • Arthur, W. B. (1994). Bounded rationality and inductive behavior (the El Farol Problem) // American Economic Review, 84(2), 406–411.
  • Beer, D. (2016). Metric Power. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK. (http://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-55649-3).
  • Campbell, D. T. (1979). Assessing the impact of planned social change // Evaluation and Program Planning, 2(1), 67–90. DOI: 10.1016/0149-7189(79)90048-x.
  • Davies, W. (2014). The Limits of Neoliberalism: Authority, Sovereignty and the Logic of Competition. United Kingdom: SAGE Publications Ltd. (http://doi.org/10.4135/9781473906075).
  • Davies, W. (2015). Spirits of neoliberalism: ‘Competitiveness’ and ‘wellbeing’ indicators as rival orders of worth (283–306) / In: R. Rottenburg, S. E. Merry, S.-J. Park and J. Mugler (Eds.), The World of Indicators. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 9http://doi. org/10.1017/CBO9781316091265.011).
  • Fioramonti, D. L. (2014). How numbers rule the world: The use and abuse of statistics in global politics. London, New York: Zed Books Ltd.
  • Graeber, D. (2015). The Utopia of Rules: On Technology, Stupidity and the Secret Joys of Bureaucracy. NY: Melville House.
  • Gray, D., Micheli, P. and Pavlov, A. (2014). Measurement Madness: Recognizing and avoiding the pitfalls of performance measurement. John Wiley & Sons.
  • Hayek, F. A. (2012). The Fatal Conceit: the Errors of Socialism. University of Chicago Press.
  • Lorenz, C. (2012). If You’re So Smart, Why Are You under Surveillance? Universities, Neoliberalism and New Public Management // Critical Inquiry, 38(3), 599–629. (http:// doi.org/10.1086/664553).
  • Markey-Towler, B. (2018). The competition and evolution of ideas in the public sphere: a new foundation for institutional theory // Journal of Institutional Economics, 1–22. (http://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137418000061).
  • Mirowski, P. and Nik-Khah, E. (2017). The Knowledge We Have Lost in Information. Oxford University Press. (https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780190270056.001.0001).
  • Muller, J. (2018). The Tyranny of Metrics. Princeton University Press. (http://doi. org/10.23943/9781400889433).
  • North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the Process of Economic Change. DOI: 10.1515/9781400829484.
  • Origgi, G. (2018). Reputation: What It Is and Why It Matters. Princeton: Princeton University Press. (http://doi.org/10.1515/9781400888597).
  • Porter, T. (1995). Trust in Numbers. Princeton University Press.
  • Taleb, N. N. (2018). Skin in the Game: Hidden Asymmetries in Daily Life. Random House
  • Unterhalter, E. (2017). Negative capability? Measuring the unmeasurable in education // Comparative Education, 53(1), 1–16. (http://doi.org/10.1080/03050068.2017.1254945).
  • Volchik, V., Klimenko, L. and Posukhova, O. (2018). Socio-economic sustainable development and the precariat: a case study of three Russian cities // Entrepreneurship and Sustainability Issues, 6(1), 411–428. (doi:10.9770/jesi.2018.6.1(25)).
Publisher: Southern Federal University
Founder: Southern Federal University
ISSN: 2073-6606